(pressing HOME will start a new search)
Privatization
Francis
M. Eubanks and Fred Peccini
Department
of Construction Science and Management
Clemson
University
Clemson, South Carolina
In an increasingly restrictive fiscal climate, governments have turned to creative ways to make the provision of public services avilable and, in some cases, possible. One of the most politically viable methods of service provision is privatization. This report will attempt to offer a brief but thorough understanding of privatization through discussions relating to its: origin; the various forms that it can take; considerations of privatization policies; financial issues and politically opposing views; and specific cases in practice, to illustrate how privatization policies have been implemented. The report concludes with a brief discussion of its importance and relevance in terms of risk and opportunity to the construction contractor. |
Introduction
Interest
in privatization has gained widespread interest and acceptance by government
policy makers as an alternative to the funding, administration and delivery of
services by the government itself. The main reasons for considering
privatization strategies pertain to increased pressures on public budgets
coupled with strong indications that the private sector, having a competitive
culture, can function with greater efficiency, at lower cost and enhanced
quality.
Privatization,
as a cost-control measure, is believed to improve economic incentives; attract
managerial and technological resources from the private sector; broaden share
ownership; and reduce public sector debt and borrowing. (Perotti,1993, p. 84).
Further, privatization can be regarded as an alternative form of public
financing, to reduce the overwhelming specter of public debt. The public
budget customarily benefits from the value-maximization aims of the private
enterprise.
Functional
Transfers: The Origins of Privatization
In
1976, the U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations (ACIR)
published a report called Pragmatic Federalism: The Reassignment of Functional
Responsibility (McManus, 1990, p.157). This work provided recommendations for
and forecasts of the shifting government functions to other tiers. The
motivation behind this report was to develop a program for allocating
government functions, particularly those that involved health and education,
to those jurisdictions that would be able to fund them appropriately.
These
"functional transfers" were forecasted to occur mainly from local to
regional to state jurisdictional responsibility, as a means to cope with
budget constraints at the smaller, local levels. Economies of scale would be
realized, thereby increasing efficiency and reducing cost. However, federal
monetary aid to state and local governments dropped substantially during the
1980s. Reagan and his "New Federalism" policy emphasized a downward
shift of functional responsibility, as opposed to the upward movement favored
by the local governments. Tax revolt movements spawned by voter referendums
such as California's Proposition 13 in 1978 legally prohibited local
governments from raising property taxes in order to replace lost federal and
state finding. In addition, state legislatures imposed constraints on the
local use of state income and sales taxes, since the states themselves were
getting pinched by the federal government.
This
tightening of revenue released primarily by Federal and secondarily, state
governments has continued through the 1980's. Under this climate, local
governments were forced to look at ways to reduce their expenditures and
capital outlays. Coupled with state and federal governments' aversion to
consider the transferring of functions from the local level to their levels,
local governments had no other option but to turn to the private sector.
Cost-cutting
measures had to be devised, which would result in various ways of providing
increased services of higher quality. Further, these proposals were encouraged
by the Reagan Administration's belief that private enterprise has an ability
superior to public entities in providing public services. Such was the
reasoning and impetus for the creation of privatization', becoming all
government's (federal, state and local) primary strategy in meeting increased
demand of services in the face of dwindling revenue.
Forms
of Privatization
Privatization,
the process whereby the enterprises of the government are transferred to the
private sector, can exist in several forms. Commonly, governments maintain
fiscal and administrative responsibility for providing the service, where the
private entity is responsible only for the actual delivery of it. Various
forms of privatization exist, among them:
Contracting
This
is the most common and popular instrument of privatization. Contracting occurs
when a government enters into a contractual agreement with a service provider,
subjecting both parties to terms and conditions set forth in the agreement.
Functional areas where contracting is commonly implemented are: transportation
(e.g. tollways, subway systems, marine terminals, and airports), health care,
social services, employment training, corrections, fire and police protection,
etc.
Voucher
Government
funds the service and issues vouchers to entitled citizens, who then redeem
them for the privately provided service. Examples of functional areas include:
social services (including food stamps and housing vouchers), education, child
care, etc.
Franchising
This
happens when a government grants a private firm monopoly privileges to provide
functions in a specified geographic area. Example include: State and national
park concessions (e.g. food services, recreation and lodging accommodations)
and management services, cable television and other utility services (e.g.
water treatment and supply).
Grants
and Subsidies
These
are moneys which are given to private enterprises to aid or encourage them in
the delivery of a necessary service. These funds are usually funnelled through
existing government agencies, for example, for employment training, ambulance
services, child care, etc.
Volunteerism
Governments
recruit private individual or enterprise time and personnel to be used in the
delivery of a service. This form, along with private donation, is a sort of
reverse subsidy of the function; the government still retains control over
fiscal and administrative considerations. The most notable example of this
form is in the private cleanup of state-owned roads and streets through
"adopt-a-highway" programs.
A
variation of this form of privatization is "self-help". The
difference lies in the fact that the volunteers are the beneficiaries of their
own efforts and actions. Neighborhood watch groups are an example of a
self‑help organization.
Private
Donation
In
addition to volunteers, governments solicit money, facilities, technology, or
equipment from private enterprises. Noted examples of donations include:
computers given to grade schools, bequeathment of land for dedicated purposes,
and auxiliary associations dedicated to raising private funds for public
entities, such as hospitals and fire protection.
Less
commonly implemented but gaining in popularity, a few forms of privatization
have to do mainly with minimizing the government's fiscal and administrative
role in providing services. Those policies that follow are perhaps indicative
of the purest form of privatization: decreasing government control of service
provision.
Asset
Sales
Usually,
when a government consolidates activities or ends programs, surplus real
estate and improvements are created. No longer performing their original
functions, the government sells these assets to private investors, who develop
them at their will. Closed military bases are an example of potential asset
sale events.
Service
Shedding
This
form occurs when a government entity transfers all its functions, including
all risks and responsibilities, to a private business entity. Theoretically,
in this scenario of functional transfer, the government is completely out of
the fiscal picture immediately after the sale. Realistically however, the
degree to which the government retains control can vary widely. Actual cases
related to this practice of privatization are discussed below. Asset sales can
be included in this form; however, the key difference is that the government's
objective is to get out of the business altogether, and therefore no longer
has a need for the service-related assets.
Public/Private
Partnerships
Alliance
of resources from both the government and a member of the private sector reduces
the reliance on employing tax revenue for service provision. The proportions of
contributed capital and resources from both sides can vary widely according to
many factors, as indicated in the example of a partnership recently formed for
the construction and operation of an infrastructure project, presented and
discussed below.
In
addition to the classes of privatization practices already discussed, other
policies can exist to foster the growth of privatization.
Deregulation
When
this occurs, regulatory barriers are being removed that formerly restricted
private firms from participating in service delivery, or have prohibited federal
funds to be attached to any project which has been privately funded or managed.
For example, the court-ordered breakup of AT&T and the subsequent creation
of "baby bells", which still sustain close regulatory oversight. This
allowed the holding company, through reorganization, to venture into areas of
competitive enterprise that were formerly prohibited by regulatory statute.
Also, through changes in government regulatory posture, an investment house may
act as much as a de facto bank, prompting legitimate banks to seek regulatory
changes allowing them to diversify into investment markets.
Tax
Incentives
By
altering the cost of a service (usually lowering it) through changes in the tax
code, tax incentives can encourage the private sector to provide it. These
incentives can be applied to any service area. Also, by shifting provisional
responsibility for services to the private sector, tax revenues can be generated
if the adopting private firm is non-profit, such as can be the case in public
housing delivery.
Further,
privatization can occur in three general areas, which any or a combination of
the above forms can serve to
accomplish:
public asset divestiture, private development of infrastructure facilities--
"project-based" privatization, and private provision of services to
the government. These areas are basically delineated by the degree of fiscal,
administrative, and operational control allocated to the parties (i.e the
government and the private firm) involved in the privatization enterprise.
Policy
Considerations of Privatization
Privatization,
or the exercise of functional transfers or divestitures to the private sector,
have several potential advantages. These advantages allow for increases in
economic efficiency, fiscal equity, political accountability, and administrative
effectiveness. Within these four areas, the following objectives of
privatization strategies are as follows (McManus, 1990, p.159)2
Privatization
strategies are expected to:
obtain
the best possible service at the lowest possible cost, in the most equitable
manner possible, while at least protecting, if not enhancing political
interests; (economic efficiency).
save
money (or maximize available money) without being too inequitable or too
politically inastute; (economic efficiency, fiscal equity, political
accountability).
get
rid of, or avoid having to deal with day-to day management responsibilities,
problem employees, and unions (where they exist), without bogging the
jurisdiction down in a legal and/or political quagmire; (administrative
effectiveness).
identify
a service delivery solution that will accommodate opposing, but more or less
equally powerful political interests, and at least protect the interests of the
decision-maker (or makers); (political accountability, administrative
effectiveness).
For
most local governments, the fiscal benefits of privatization usually outweigh
the political ones. As seen in recent campaigns and subsequent elections
recently, candidate's platforms indicate that economics and politics, especially
in light of the current recession, are inseparable, For example, the current
health care debate is more closely associated with ideas about cutting cost
through enhanced efficiency, rather than exclusively considering quality.'
According
to a survey conducted to prove hypotheses on the political acceptability and
viability of privatization, functional divestiture strategies are generally
given a favorable rating by local governments (McManus, 1991, p.163 ff). Given
the financial constraints imposed by the federal government as well as by legal
revenue-raising restrictions and vehement voter-taxpayer opposition to any tax
hike, results of the survey indicate that:
There
is still a strong level of support among a sample of county and municipal chief
budget officers for public sector divestiture of assets to other levels of
government, despite the current focus of privatization as the cost-cutting
technique. Instead of implementing privatization schemes like service shedding
or asset divestiture, there still exists a practice of shifting responsibilities
to other government levels, agencies, or departments. This can be labelled as
merely an attempt to "pass the buck".
Partial
divestiture of functions via privatization is generally more acceptable than
full and permanent divestiture.
Smaller
cities less commonly use privatization strategies than do their larger
counterparts.
However,
among all governments expressing an interest permanently to divest functions to
the private sector, privatization strategies were most extensive in smaller
cities.
Caught
in the bind of fiscal restraints brought on by decreasing tax revenues and
funding from higher government levels, it is critical to the existence of
smaller jurisdictions to be able to access private capital for their necessary
functions, if only to deflect taxpayer resentment. Support levels at all tiers
of government must be raised so that legislation can be enacted to enable
implementation of privatization measures, especially at the local level.
Financing
Privatization
Privatization
has become more of a populist idea than has "denationalization", which
has been seen as a policy to shift large government programs to proportionately
large, corporate firms. Popular resistance to denationalization relies in the
idea that with the transfer of functions comes the highly concentrated transfer
of funds and with it, disproportionate power and wealth.
As
opposed the denationalization, privatization is perceived to be more favorable
in terms of "equality of equity", in that many privatization plans
include asset sales of government function to corporation with large numbers of
individual shareholders with more equalized voting rights, For the political
viability necessary for privatization strategies to succeed, it must be obvious
that shareholder's capital will supplant taxpayer's contributions. Historically,
taxes, even though referred to as "revenue", is more precisely
"equity" or "contributed capital". Indeed, taxpayers demand
a return on their investment in the form of services rendered. However, it is
the high cost of these services, financed by the taxpayers, that has led to
charges of government waste, abuse, and inefficient use of funds. Privatization
is widely espoused by government officials and constituents alike as a solution
-even a panacea-- for all budgetary problems.
Privatization
of government enterprises, in order to work, requires financing both to create
private ownership and to maintain continued activities of the private entity,
Financing requirements can vary form company to company, with varying degrees of
quality and size of the business. Additionally, other external factors can exist
as to: the political and cultural enmity towards admitting foreign private
capital, the availability of private domestic capital, and the degree of risk
and equity investment that local investors are willing to take and make.
During
privatization phase-in, funding of the private entity usually is accomplished
through a combination of government subsidies (direct payments, guaranteed loans
and government guaranteed lines of credit) and capital raised through debt and
equity markets. As dependence on government contributions wanes, there is an
increased need for long and short term capital for the procurement of new
facilities, equipment and technology, as well as for modernization of any
existing physical plant which is taken over as part of the privatization plan.
One
of the most critical components of financing the privatization of government
functions is in providing for working capital requirements of the private
business entity. Obviously, the best strategy for raising working capital is
achieved through the generation of profits, rather than raising current assets
(cash) through taking on long-term-debt (notes and bonds) or issuing new equity
(stocks). If the need then arises to raise cash through debt-loading, financial
institutions are more inclined to risk depositor's funds if it is clear that
most of the financing of capital equipment and facilities comes from the
periodic difference between revenues and expenses, namely profit.
Planning
is absolutely necessary in financing privatization. Internal and external
factors, some of which are noted above, must be considered. The phasing-in
process of privatization occurs simultaneously with its financing; it must begin
before functions are transferred and followed through to the point where the
private enterprise can stand on its own financial footing. Again, it is a
generally accepted notion that a private company, since it is more effective in
attaining the noble goals of high quality and public service, is more likely to
exceed in its endeavors to provide traditional government-provided services.
Also, direct accountability of management to shareholders is a much more
effective means of ensuring the success of the private entity, In government-owned
enterprises, managers are not accountable to taxpayers. They must only answer to
government bureaucrats at best and their own agendas at worst, both actions or
inactions resulting in the kind of gross inefficiencies that government
enterprises are perceived to practice.
Indeed,
it is the ability of privatization plans to attract private capital that makes
the transfer of functions to the private sector possible. For example,
privatizing the operation of existing airports provides access to private
capital markets for construction. Combined with federal grants and passenger
facility charges, the bond markets enable the airports in this country to pay
for improvements. (Merwin, 1991, p 27.)
Pros
and Cons of Privatization
Governments
at all levels in this country have always relied on the private sector for the
delivery of public services, as opposed to foreign governments which solely rely
on the direct employment of its citizens to carry out its functions. Other
industrialized democracies, such as those found in Europe, still have
nationalized mega-industries, most notably in telecommunications and
transportation. In the U.S. however, there has been a trend toward limiting
government intervention, since the deregulation movement in the late 1970s.
Further, under a sky of conservatism, tax revenues have dropped and costs have
risen, moving governments to use the instruments of privatization in pursuit of
public policy goals.
Among
the arguments expressed in favor of privatization are those which have an
emphasis on efficiency and effectiveness, responsiveness, and political
ideology.
Greater
efficiencies and cost containment can be realized in the private sector
Private
firms can respond more quickly than can government agencies to changing
conditions.
There
is a strong ideological undercurrent that supports private over public action
(State of SC, 1991, p. 7-8).
Taking
the opposite point of view, critics of privatization allege that the various
forms do not live up to expectations; measurements of the performance of cost-containment
measures, for example, indicate that taxpayers are not benefitting from the
program. Therefore, critics believe that reliance on private sector delivery
should be kept to a minimum. It is contended that so little can be known about
the real costs, benefits, and impacts of privatization that it should be
implemented with the highest degree of prudence. Basically, the argument against
privatization is the question of control and dominion, in addition to whether or
not privatization of a particular service results in a substantial cost savings
to the taxpayer.
Privatization
undermines the public commitment to ensure the efficient, effective, and
equitable distribution and availability of public services.
Privatization
reduces service quality, fails to contain costs, and may, in fact, lead to
higher costs for service delivery and benefit distribution.
Privatization
undermines government's role as the ultimate focus of accountability and need to
insure access to and availability of public services and benefits (State of SC,
1991, p. 9-10).
In
addition, proponents and detractors have made their respective cases for and
against contracting, the most common and popular instrument of privatization.
Following are sample statements (after Peters, 1991, p. 58-59), supporting the
opposing arguments.
For:
Competition
between contract bidders results in reduced cost or enhanced quality or both.
The
growth of government, mainly in terms of employment, is contained.
Specifically
skilled workers can be obtained as needed, without regulatory constraints
imposed as part of civil service requirements.
The
size of a program can be adjusted without employee layoffs or negotiations.
The
entire cost of a service is more visible, thereby allowing for cost comparison
among various contractors' services.
Government
managers can concentrate on planning and monitoring activities rather than
administering day-to-day operations. This situation would tend to allow better
management and objectivity in evaluating the progress of operations.
The
private service provider is more likely to be held more closely accountable than
the former government provider, especially because costs cannot as easily be
passed on to the taxpayer
The
need to define the scope of services clearly, as well as to monitor the
performance of the contractor, produces meaningful management information that
is often otherwise available.
Against:
Demoralization
of public employees may develop, along with possible consequent job actions and
costly legal challenges of privatization measures.
Governmental
accountability and control is reduced.
Public
policy objectives may be breached, such as equal opportunity employment and
veteran's preference programs.
Competition
may not exist in a particular service area, and once a company is awarded a
contract it may be renewed almost automatically, thus limiting competition.
Responding
quickly to emergencies or major changes in service needs may be difficult
because of contract constraints.
Close
monitoring of the contractor's activities is needed to ensure contract
compliance.
Contractor's
may acquire undue political power.
Contracting
may "commercialize" non-profit social service agencies, causing them
to diminish their role as a social conscience.
Case
Studies: Toronto Airport, Dulles Highway and Puerto Rico Bridge
Currently,
there is a crisis in meeting the needs of our national infrastructure; this
nation's highways, bridges, water supply and sewer treatment systems, etc. are
rapidly degrading to the point of being unsafe. In addition to the need for
replacement of existing infrastructure, the needs of an ever-increasing
population place increasing demands on an already user-saturated system.
Augmentation of the system, as well as its needed restoration, will require a
substantial capital investment. For example, in a recently completed study, New
Jersey identified required investment in transportation, water, solid waste,
energy, and telecommunications infrastructure of $95 billion over the next 10
years (David, 1992, p.50). Keep in mind that this figure reflects the capital
expenditures of just one state. Although different states have various
infrastructure needs, imagine the staggering sum that must be raised to satisfy
future infrastructure needs. As has been noted previously, taxpayers will
continue to resist any revenue-raising maneuvers by the government, especially
those that result in new taxes. Privatization is commonly seen by politicians
(especially those who may want to gain reelection) as the last refuge for
obtaining infrastructure funds.
Specifically,
the majority of transportation infrastructure is literally crumbling. Current
maintenance programs and procedures can no longer patch up the system. Private
capital must be used for transportation infrastructure improvement and
expansion. According to the Privatization Council, a non-profit consortium of
private firms and government agencies interested in the advancement of public-private
partnerships, transportation is particularly well-suited to private
participation. In order to attract private capital, tollroads and toll bridges,
airports and rail systems can generate enough revenue from user fees and
integrated commercial development.
To
foster support for the raising of private capital, recent federal legislation
promotes private participation in surface transportation. While providing for
increasing levels of federal funding of state and local transportation projects,
The Intermodal Surface Transportation Efficiency Act of 1991, commonly referred
to as ISTEA, allows states to integrate federal, state, and private funds in a
privately owned tollway. This cross-pollination of capital had never been legal
prior to the passage of ISTEA. Also, ISTEA enables states to establish
Transportation Revolving Loan Funds to support private tollway owners. One of
the most important elements of ISTEA is that it permits the Secretary of
Transportation to waive restrictions placed on asset sales of surface
transportation facilities that had been previously funded by federal monies.
This had formerly been one of the greatest hindrances to privatization: asset
sales of state-owned enterprises had been halted under the specter of litigation
and revenue‑withholding by the federal government. The federal government
would often seek the return of all funds, funneled into the enterprise over its
life, as a condition of the asset sale to a private entity. After the
declaration of privatization policy as promulgated in ISTEA, the federal
government is no longer likely to exercise such action.
Theoretically,
privatization's strength exists in its ability to access and tap into the
private capital markets to replace public funds which simply no longer exist.
The central core of the argument for privatization is that greater efficiency
and therefore lower costs can be realized, resulting in a higher ratio of
service returns per tax dollar (or more precisely, "taxpayer
capital"). In order to see how privatization is currently working in this
regard, one must look to the record of recent privatized projects. To
investigate the use of privatization and private capital and its current degree
of success, several actual cases are presented below, specifically regarding
transportation infrastructure projects.
The
Tollroad
The
Dulles Tollroad Extension, linking Dulles International Airport with Leesburg,
Va., a suburb of Washington D.C., could be held as a model for privately-owned,
for profit highways, designed to provide badly needed infrastructure. Scheduled
to be opened in late 1993, the Dulles Extension will cost $180 million for
design and construction and an equal amount to cover costs in its early years of
service. Operation and maintenance costs, as well as the costs of capital (e.g.
legal and brokerage fees) and interest expenses will be covered by tolls, which
are "user fees". Ordinarily, for non-toll highways, these costs are
directly borne by tax revenue. Only those who actually use the tollroad will pay
all costs from capitalization to maintenance. In the case of the Dulles
Extension, user fees will also generate profits, forecasted to be upwards of 30
percent of equity over 40 years. Also, the project is expected to generate $550
million in taxes over the same period. Without accounting for the time value of
money, this represents $900 million that will be retained in government
treasuries. At least in theory, this money can be applied to a number of areas,
such as income tax abatement or deficit reduction.
The
Bridge
The
San Jose Lagoon Bridge, linking Puerto Rico's Marin International Airport with
San Juan's financial district is setting a precedent for similar projects in the
U.S. In effect, a public/private partnership was formed with the melding of
public and private financing. While private capital is scarce in Puerto Rico, it
was still possible for the public and private enterprises to join forces. Laws
enabling the issuance of tax-free government-guaranteed revenue bonds for
private projects were specifically repealed in the 1986 Tax Reform Act'.
However, Puerto was exempt since it is considered a separate tax jurisdiction by
the IRS. $117 million in bonds were issued in this manner and combined with the
private organization's $9.4 million. Autopistas de Puerto Rico (APR), the
private entity formed as a general partnership specifically for the development
of this bridge, will manage the construction of the bridge, operate it, and
receive most of the toll revenues. Under the agreement struck with the
Commonwealth, control of the bridge will revert back to the government after 35
years.
Controversy
has been raised over whether APR is assuming a proportional share of the risk in
the investment. Also included in the agreement was a guarantee that, in the
event that traffic flows do not come close to projections in the first six
years, APR has the right to terminate the contract. Effectively, the government
is insuring the private entity against its greatest risk: suffering a return on
equity below acceptable returns. It is somewhat odd that APR, being a more
efficient, private entity, would need such special guarantees. However, it is
expected that efficiencies, with the recognized savings that can be expected,
will be realized over the course of operations. In the absence of substantial
private capital, public funding can enhance whatever amount of private capital
that is available.
The
political environment can also affect the terms which are reached in these
public/private partnerships, which are effectively quasi-public arrangements. A
balance had to be found in the level of state-provided capital. The government
knew that an expensive arrangement would cost it votes; on the other hand, if
the government were too conservative in their funding, their miserly approach
could table the project. The terms of the agreement finally ratified by both
parties included contingencies that if the internal rate of returns exceeded 19
percent, profits would be split 40/60, with the government getting 60 percent.
Above 22 percent, the split would be 15/85, with APR getting the smaller piece (Reingold,,
1993, p.39). APR receives the right to exercise the termination option in return
for having their profits limited. However, it is also somewhat of an anomaly for
the government to agree to a contract where the party who has most control over
profit maximization (i.e. cost minimization) has no incentive to do so. The
greater the internal rate of return on this project, the lower the profits are
to be retained for the private company.
The
Airport Terminal
By
the mid-1980s, Toronto's Lester B. Pearson International Airport had evolved
into an embarrassment of grave proportions for the Canadian government. Its
inefficiencies, resulting in high costs and travel delays, forced the federal
government in Ottawa to seek ways to improve the airport's facilities and
functions. However, the government was experiencing a low supply of cash, with
no viable public alternatives for funding.
In
1987, still faced with budget woes, and prior to relinquishing control of
airports to independent regional authorities, the Canada Ministry of
Transportation elicited bids from private business concerns interested in
building a new terminal at Pearson International. The contract was eventually
awarded to a joint venture headed up by Lockheed Airline Terminal. In February
1991, just three years after construction was begun, Pearson's third
international terminal, called Trillium, was opened. Since then, it has become a
shining example of what privatization can accomplish. It was built in less than
half the estimated time and is run by 65% fewer people than comparable
facilities in the U.S.
Although
its opening coincided with the Gulf War and its private owner has been affected
by Canada's still present recession, Lockheed reports that it has had a positive
cash flow since opening day. According to the Canadian government, the project
has been highly profitable, therefore generating a substantial amount of tax
revenue.
However,
not everyone is happy about the precedent set in Canada. Airlines are afraid
that the lessor of their real estate, another private company like themselves,
would immediately raise landing and gate fees to cover its debt service on the
purchase of airport infrastructure. They argue that they will be unable to pass
these higher costs onto the flying public, since they are still involved in
heated fare wars with other airlines. Also objectionable to the airlines is the
inclusion of retail areas in the development of airport terminals. The anxiety
is that private concerns will pass the extra costs of development onto the
already overburdened airlines. More realistically, retail space can provide a
revenue enhancement to the project, leading to a greater capacity to cover
investment costs and interest expenses.
To
answer these concerns, governments respond that they are simply trying to sell
assets as a means of raising sorely needed cash. Private entities who take over
government functions must protect these assets by maintaining efficiency, while
controlling their costs, enhancing their revenue opportunities, and maximizing
their returns. It is clear in their resistance of privatization that the airline
lobby sees the privatization of airline terminals as a subterfuge to undermine
their power.
Conclusion
What
does it all mean to the construction contractor?
It
is the ultimate goal of privatization, at least from a political point of view,
to see that services and facilities are rendered at the most efficient and
effective level for the citizenry. It may at first seem that implementation of
privatization would cause a downward shift in the volume of services needed, due
to the generally recognized efficiencies of private industry provision. Under
this scenario, private entities who have efficient service delivery programs may
not require the level of facility usage that the government formally needed.
However, opportunities will exist for the construction contractor if and when
broad privatization policies are promulgated and implemented. This may come from
the potential opening up of capital markets to public investments, especially in
the area of infrastructure construction and repair. Inducements for this release
of capital may come through reforms in the tax code, as well as through changes
in governmental policy toward facility procurement.
In
light of these changes and reforms, construction contractors may see a dramatic
shift towards providing services for owners of functions which were formally
contracted by the government. Risks are present-risks exist as to the degree of
financial stability of a private, as opposed to government, owner. Since many
governments on the state and local levels have, from time to time, sustained
budget shortfalls-even to the brink of bankruptcy--they generally have the power
to raise funds to continue projects. Governments will always be in business.
Lenders are loathe were allowed to foreclose on government properties; if they
did, the entire economy would suffer, including the lenders themselves. The lack
of "solvency" of the federal government, coupled with its ability to
expand the deficit with increasing debt loading, illustrates this point. In the
alternative, private companies who take over the responsibility for
infrastructure improvements are subject to bankruptcy laws. The difference in
this case arises out of the type of risk of the particular enterprise, that risk
is deemed commercial, rather than that of the sheltered sovereign variety. As
such, the construction contractor who provides services to the private provider
runs the risk of suffering work stoppages due to the absence of cash flow that
may arise when a private entity seeks protection from its creditors.
If
as much as they are interested, a construction contractor can use its financial
resources to invest in an equity participation in an infrastructure project. In
these cases, the contractor can act as developer: funding and overseeing the
project, as well as building it. Risks can be greater in this situation, since
the lack of separation of responsibilities can expose the contractor-developer
to a broader spectrum of liability. Nevertheless, the returns can be
correspondingly high. The degree to which the contractor seeks involvement in a
project depends on its willingness to accept a certain level of risk. To reduce
risk, a smaller equity involvement could be considered, in that the exposure to
unacceptable risk may be eradicated.
A
construction contractor can also use the "turnkey" approach to
contracting. In this approach, the contractor provides financing for the
project, as well as design and construction services. After the project is
complete and ready for delivery, payment is rendered, and the key is
"turned over" to the owner. This owner can either be the government
who needs the project in order to provide the public service, or the private
entity which has partially or fully taken over the service that was formally
provided by the government enterprise.
A
further approach to take advantage of opportunities arising out of privatization
policies can be realized through joint-ventures. Fiscal partnerships can be
created with facility operators for the design and construction of public
service-facilities. After completion of the project, the joint-venture would be
dissolved, leaving the facility operator to contract with the government for
service provision.
References
Castillo,
Rosendo J. (1987), "Financing Privatization", in Hanke, Stephen H.,
(ed.), Privatization and Development (International Center for Economic Growth,
San Francisco, California), pp. 119-126.
David,
Irwin T. (1992), "Privatization: Solving the Infrastructure Crisis",
Construction Business
Review
(May/June), pp. 50-55.
Hass,
Nancy (1993), "Cleared for Takeoff", Financial World (August 3), pp.
40-41. (1993), "Psst, Wanna Buy a Bridge?", Financial World (August
3), pp. 30-35.
McManus,
Susan A. (1990), "Decentralizing Expenditures and Responsibilities",
in Bennett, Robert J., (ed.), Decentralization, Local Governments, and Markets
(Oxford University Press, New York), pp. 157-171.
Merwin,
Donald P. (1991), "Privatization Hits the Roads", Highway and Heavy
Construction (November), pp. 26-27. Perotti, Enrico C., and Guney, Serhat E.
(1993), "The Structure of Privatization Plans", Financial Management
(Spring), pp. 84‑98.
Peters,
Terry (1991), "Public Services and the Private Sector", in Kemp, Roger
L., (ed.), Privatization: The Provision of Public Services by the Private Sector
(McFarland & Company, Jefferson, North Carolina), pp. 53-59.
Reingold,
Jennifer (1993), "A Bridge Too Far?", Financial World (August 3), pp.
38-39.
State
of South Carolina (1991), Privatization: An Alternative Approach to Public
Policy Implementation (State Reorganization Commission, Columbia, South
Carolina).